Back to History Current Version

Why do people ‘pay not to go the gym’?

Last registered on May 08, 2019

Pre-Trial

Trial Information

General Information

Title
Why do people ‘pay not to go the gym’?
RCT ID
AEARCTR-0004121
Initial registration date
April 26, 2019

Initial registration date is when the trial was registered.

It corresponds to when the registration was submitted to the Registry to be reviewed for publication.

First published
May 08, 2019, 1:39 PM EDT

First published corresponds to when the trial was first made public on the Registry after being reviewed.

Locations

Primary Investigator

Affiliation
University of East Anglia

Other Primary Investigator(s)

PI Affiliation
University of East Anglia
PI Affiliation
Warwick Business School

Additional Trial Information

Status
In development
Start date
2019-05-01
End date
2020-09-30
Secondary IDs
Abstract
Behavioural economists often justify paternalistic policies by claiming that individuals have self-acknowledged self-control problems (SASCPs) they want other people or agencies to help them overcome. SASCPs are modelled by assuming individuals have ‘true’ preferences which they know but fail to act on. This approach promises to provide preference-based criteria for evaluating behavioural interventions, and to counter the objection that these are unacceptably paternalistic. But how prevalent SASCPs are remains an open question. The existence of true preferences has been questioned (Sugden, Community of Advantage, 2018). Laibson (AER, 2015) has noted that, in markets, individuals rarely pay for self-commitment.

A putative counter-example is the case of gym users choosing membership tariffs rather than cheaper pay-as-you-go (PAYG) ones – ‘paying not to go to the gym’ (DellaVigna and Malmendier, AER, 2016). It is often argued that membership is chosen as a commitment device. However, there are alternative explanations: people may over-predict future consumption; the fixed membership fee provides insurance for people who are uncertain about their future preferences; by consolidating charges into a single payment, people reduce the ‘pain of paying’.

This study develops a lab experiment that creates an environment analogous with the gym case. Each subject allocates time between ‘study’ episodes and watching an entertaining video. The subject is then tested on her knowledge of the book and paid according to her score. Before the video starts, she ranks a set of alternative tariffs for buying access to chapters, and is allocated to one of these. The experiment is set up to allow subjects to rank membership tariffs above PAYG ones but, if assigned to a membership tariff, to ‘pay not to study’. Our design discriminates between commitment, over-prediction, insurance and pain-of-paying explanations.
External Link(s)

Registration Citation

Citation
Isoni, Andrea, Robert Sugden and Jiwei Zheng. 2019. "Why do people ‘pay not to go the gym’?." AEA RCT Registry. May 08. https://doi.org/10.1257/rct.4121-1.0
Former Citation
Isoni, Andrea, Robert Sugden and Jiwei Zheng. 2019. "Why do people ‘pay not to go the gym’?." AEA RCT Registry. May 08. https://www.socialscienceregistry.org/trials/4121/history/46189
Experimental Details

Interventions

Intervention(s)
The planned trial is a laboratory experiment. As explained in the ‘Experimental Design’ section, the experiment investigates participants’ rankings of four alternative contracts for buying access to a ‘virtue good’ (study episodes in a setting in which video entertainment is available as a tempting alternative). Every participant reports his/her ranking of the contracts. For each participant, a random process selects two potential contracts; the participant is then assigned to whichever of those two contracts he/she ranked higher, and his/her subsequent choices between study and entertainment are recorded. We test alternative hypotheses about how people behave within this experimental environment. In a design of this kind, there is no distinction between ‘intervention’ and ‘non-intervention’ and so there is no ‘control group’ in the sense of a group of participants who experience non-intervention.
Intervention Start Date
2019-05-01
Intervention End Date
2019-12-31

Primary Outcomes

Primary Outcomes (end points)
For each participant: rankings of the four contracts; number of chapters read under allocated contract; responses to questions about perceptions of stages 2 and 3 of the experiment.
Primary Outcomes (explanation)

Secondary Outcomes

Secondary Outcomes (end points)
For each participant: ratings of the videos; allocation of time between video and study; number of occasions on which 'time left' was checked; test score; demographics.
Secondary Outcomes (explanation)

Experimental Design

Experimental Design
Background

A ‘virtue good’ is a good for which individual episodes of consumption are unpleasant, but regular consumption produces long-term benefits. Economists have argued that these features create self-control problems that consumers can overcome by buying virtue goods on ‘membership’ contracts (i.e., paying a fixed price for unlimited consumption over a given period) rather than ‘pay-as-you-go’ contracts (i.e., paying separately for each unit of the good consumed). Della Vigna and Malmendier (American Economic Review 2006) find that many gym users choose a membership contract but then choose a level of use that would have cost less on a pay-as-you-go contract (‘paying not to go to the gym’). We consider four possible explanations for this finding:
• Self-control (the most commonly cited explanation): membership contracts are chosen as a means of overcoming self-control problems
• Pain of paying: people prefer to consolidate several small payments into one larger one, and/or prefer to ‘get it over with’ by paying in advance of consumption.
• Prediction error: people over-predict future consumption of virtue goods, and wrongly expect membership contracts to be cheaper.
• Insurance: people are uncertain about their future consumption; because of risk- or ambiguity-aversion, they prefer to pay a known sum of money rather than to be uncertain about how much they will pay.
We aim to discriminate between these hypotheses by using a laboratory experiment in which the virtue good is studying for a test.

Experimental design

In Stage 1 of the experiment, each subject sees short clips of seven videos, and rates them on dimensions such as ‘enjoyable’ and ‘exciting’. She is told that, during the experiment, she will be able to watch one of these videos; she chooses which this will be. It is intended that each subject will be able to choose a video that will be a tempting alternative to study. Responses to the rating questions will be used to check that this intention has been achieved.
In Stage 2, the procedures for the remainder of the experiment are explained. Each subject is told that she will be tested on her knowledge of ‘facts’ about an imaginary country and paid according to her test score. She is given an ‘account’ which is credited with an opening balance of money. She is told about four alternative contracts (described below) for buying access to eight ‘book chapters’ which contain the relevant facts. She ranks the contracts in order of preference. Two contracts are then selected by a random mechanism that gives each possible pair of contracts a positive probability of being selected. The subject is allocated to whichever of these two contracts she ranked higher.
Stage 3 is a 21-minute period during which the chosen video runs continuously. During this time, the subject has opportunities to ‘study’. Study takes place in one-minute episodes during which the video is running but cannot be seen or heard. A subject can initiate a study episode at any time, except that each episode must be preceded by a least one minute of watching the video. In each episode, the subject views one chapter and can take ‘notes’ about the information it contains. Access to chapters is charged according to the subject’s contract.
In Stage 4, each subject takes a multiple-choice test. The test questions are randomly selected from the facts in the book. Subjects are able to consult their notes during the test. Subjects know they will earn money according to the number of correct answers they give in the test.
In Stage 5, each subject answers a questionnaire about her perceptions of Stages 2 and 3. The questions relating to Stage 2 are designed to elicit attitudes that correspond or conflict with our alternative hypotheses about the criteria individuals use to rank contracts. The questions relating to Stage 3 elicit how far the subject perceived that stage as posing a self-control problem and whether she believes she made errors in predicting how many chapters she would view.
In Stage 6, each subject writes a short review of the video she has watched, and a short comment that could be posted on YouTube.
In the final Stage 7, each subject is told her earnings from the test, which are credited to her account. She is then paid according to the closing balance in her account. Opening balances and contract terms will be set so that closing balances cannot be negative.

Contracts

The four contracts are defined as follows, in terms of parameters x and y, where y > x.
• In the Book contract (a membership contract), the subject buys access to all eight chapters at once before the beginning of the video, making a single payment of £8x, deducted from her balance before the video starts.
• In the Chapter contract (a pay-as-you-go contract), the subject buys access to one chapter at a time, if and when she starts a new study episode. For each chapter viewed, there is a payment of £y, deducted from her balance when the choice to view is made.
• In the Book-rebate contract (BR), the subject buys access to all eight chapters at once before the beginning of the video, making a single payment of £8x, deducted from her balance before the video starts. If the average deduction per chapter viewed is greater than £y, a rebate equal to the difference is added to her balance after the end of the video.
• In the Chapter-rebate contract (CR), the subject buys access to one chapter at a time, if and when she starts a new study episode. For each chapter viewed, there is a payment of £y, deducted from her balance when the choice to view is made. If the total deduction is greater than £8x, a rebate equal to the difference is added to her balance after the end of the video.
Thus, if q is the number of chapters read, Book is less (more) costly than Chapter if q is greater than (less than) 8x/y. BR and CR are exactly equivalent in terms of net payments, and always equal to the cheaper of Book and Chapter.
A major purpose of the experiment is to investigate inconsistencies between subjects’ ex ante rankings of Book relative to Chapter and their choices about how much to study. There is over-commitment (‘paying not to study’) if a subject ranks Book above Chapter, is allocated to Book, and chooses q < 8x/y. There is under-commitment if a subject ranks Chapter above Book, is allocated to Chapter, and chooses q > 8x/y. Intuitively, inconsistencies are most likely to be observed if the values of x and y induce an approximately equal split between subjects who rank Book above Chapter and subjects with the opposite ranking. We will use pilot studies to fine-tune these values to achieve this. Since inconsistencies can be observed only when subjects are allocated to whichever of Book and Chapter they rank higher, we need there to be adequate numbers of such observations. To ensure this, the random mechanism that selects pairs of contracts in Stage 2 will select {Book, Chapter} with greater probability than the other pairs.

Hypotheses and tests

All four hypotheses imply that (after allowing for random ‘error’), over-commitment is more frequent than under-commitment. However, they have different implications about how BR and CR are ranked in relation to each other and to Book and Chapter.
The prediction error and insurance hypotheses assume that the individual maximizes expected utility, given her beliefs about her future utility function. Within this theoretical framework, BR and CR are exactly equivalent and weakly dominate Book and Chapter. Thus, both hypotheses imply that BR and CR are ranked equally or randomly, and that both are ranked above Book and Chapter. In contrast, the other two hypotheses allow ‘anomalous’ rankings of BR and CR.
The self-control hypothesis assumes that the individual has a ‘planning self’ which chooses between contracts and an ‘impulsive self’ which chooses how much to study. Study has greater weight in the preferences of the planning self. The planning self correctly predicts the choices of the impulsive self and treats these as constraints. Since both selves view BR and CR as equivalent, and both prefer low marginal prices for study, BR and CR are ranked equally or randomly relative to each other and above Chapter. But because it can be used as a self-control device, Book may be ranked above BR and CR.
According to the pain-of-paying hypothesis, the individual has a ceteris paribus preference for earlier payments over later payments and for consolidating small payments into large ones. These assumptions imply a strict preference for BR over CR, and weak preferences for BR over Book, and for CR over Chapter. We will use the experimental data to test whether these anomalies occur. Conditional on finding evidence of overall over-commitment, we will interpret these tests as tests of the respective hypotheses.
The prediction error and insurance hypotheses do not predict anomalies in the rankings of BR or CR. But if our data disconfirm the self-control and pain-of-paying hypotheses, the surviving hypotheses gain credibility.
In interpreting the results of the experiment, we will also use the questionnaire data collected in Stage 5. The questions about Stages 2 and 3 provide evidence that can support (or fail to support) each of the hypotheses. In particular, these questions discriminate between the prediction error and insurance hypotheses. They also complement the behavioral tests of the self-control and pain-of-paying hypotheses. For example, Stage 2 responses might provide evidence that many subjects thought about self-control when ranking contracts, and Stage 3 responses might provide evidence that many subjects were conscious of facing self-control problems when choosing whether to study. Such findings would constitute direct and indirect evidence in support of the self-control hypothesis.
Experimental Design Details
Randomization Method
Randomization (to determine which two contracts are relevant for each participant) will be by a quasi-random number generator.
Randomization Unit
Individual subject.
Was the treatment clustered?
No

Experiment Characteristics

Sample size: planned number of clusters
Treatment not clustered.
Sample size: planned number of observations
We have a target of 200 experimental participants. We will end data collection after the experimental session that includes the 200th participant.
Sample size (or number of clusters) by treatment arms
There is only one treatment.
Minimum detectable effect size for main outcomes (accounting for sample design and clustering)
IRB

Institutional Review Boards (IRBs)

IRB Name
School of Economics Research Ethics Committee, University of East Anglia
IRB Approval Date
2019-02-21
IRB Approval Number
0286

Post-Trial

Post Trial Information

Study Withdrawal

There is information in this trial unavailable to the public. Use the button below to request access.

Request Information

Intervention

Is the intervention completed?
No
Data Collection Complete
Data Publication

Data Publication

Is public data available?
No

Program Files

Program Files
Reports, Papers & Other Materials

Relevant Paper(s)

Reports & Other Materials