Attacking Tax Evasion in Production Networks: Theory and Evidence from Paraguay

Last registered on October 04, 2023

Pre-Trial

Trial Information

General Information

Title
Attacking Tax Evasion in Production Networks: Theory and Evidence from Paraguay
RCT ID
AEARCTR-0012208
Initial registration date
September 28, 2023

Initial registration date is when the trial was registered.

It corresponds to when the registration was submitted to the Registry to be reviewed for publication.

First published
October 04, 2023, 4:10 PM EDT

First published corresponds to when the trial was first made public on the Registry after being reviewed.

Locations

Region

Primary Investigator

Affiliation
Columbia University

Other Primary Investigator(s)

PI Affiliation
Inter-American Development Bank
PI Affiliation
Columbia University

Additional Trial Information

Status
On going
Start date
2021-01-01
End date
2024-06-30
Secondary IDs
Prior work
This trial does not extend or rely on any prior RCTs.
Abstract
The creation of a tax system that raises substantial revenues efficiently and equitably is one
of the central challenges in economic development. In large part, this relies on the creation of
the capacity to enforce taxes effectively—to reduce tax evasion. Doing this requires a detailed
understanding of the drivers of tax evasion and the optimal allocation of extremely scarce tax
enforcement resources. Our project combines new theory and a Randomized Controlled Trial
(RCT) in Paraguay to provide new insights into tax evasion by firms, the strength of enforcement
spillovers through production networks, and how to optimally target enforcement activities.
External Link(s)

Registration Citation

Citation
Best, Michael, Gaston Pierri and Evan Sadler. 2023. "Attacking Tax Evasion in Production Networks: Theory and Evidence from Paraguay." AEA RCT Registry. October 04. https://doi.org/10.1257/rct.12208-1.0
Experimental Details

Interventions

Intervention(s)
The intervention in the first experiment consists of sending notices to taxpayers suspected of underreporting
their taxable sales, based on the work of Carrillo, Pomeranz, and Singhal (2017). For
each taxpayer-month we calculated the sum of sales made by that taxpayer as reported by their clients in third-party information reports (“libros de compras”) annexed to the clients’ VAT returns. If this amount was larger than the total sales reported by the taxpayer by at least
10,000,000 Guaranies (around USD 7,000), that taxpayer-month was eligible to receive a notice.
Intervention Start Date
2022-08-15
Intervention End Date
2024-01-31

Primary Outcomes

Primary Outcomes (end points)
Do firms that receive the intervention declare more sales? Less inputs? Pay more taxes?
Is the discrepancy between the seller's VAT reports and the sum of the buyers' purchases report reduced by the intervention? Is the discrepancy between the seller's bilateral sales reports and the buyer's bilateral purchases report reduced by the intervention?
Do the clients of firms that received the intervention change their behaviour?
Do the suppliers of firms that received the intervention change their behaviour?
Primary Outcomes (explanation)

Secondary Outcomes

Secondary Outcomes (end points)
Do firms update their tax declaration? When do they make these amendments? Do firms pay more taxes on the declarations for which there were discrepancies?
Secondary Outcomes (explanation)

Experimental Design

Experimental Design
We randomly assign taxpayers to receive notices. The randomization method is optimized to allow for the detection of spillovers.
Experimental Design Details
The experiment is carried out in 4 waves.

In waves 1 and 2, We pursue a saturation design, common in experiments seeking to measure spillovers (Baird,
Bohren, McIntosh, & ¨ Ozler, 2018). To do this, we first create a network of indirect linkages
formed by pairs of clients sharing a common supplier. The idea is that treating that common
supplier may have indirect effects on any of their clients, both those mentioned in the notification
as well as those not mentioned.
1. Create clusters of suppliers based on who their clients are. To do this, we first create a
network of clients where links are formed between pairs of clients who share a supplier. We
then partition this network of 185,119 clients into 6,486 clusters using the Leiden algorithm
(Traag, Dooren, & Nesterov, 2011). We then assign each of the suppliers to one cluster
based on which cluster of clients they supply to the most.
2. We randomly assign clusters to 0%, 50% or 100% saturation rates of eligible taxpayers.
3. We choose our sample of 500 taxpayers for wave 1 following the clusters’ assigned saturation
rates.
4. We chose our sample of 1,000 taxpayers for wave 2 from the remaining eligible taxpayers
following the clusters’ assigned saturation rates.

In waves 3 & 4 the treatment assignment protocol was refined to maximize statistical power. Our choice of experimental design and parameters has been guided by the work of a team of econometricians. They compared the statistical power of several different possible experimental designs given the structure of our network, to test for direct and spillover effects. They also searched for the optimal parameters under these candidate designs.

The resulting optimal design is a split-graph design. In that design, firms are treated at random, stratifying the randomization by type $x$ (determined by their degree and by their connections to other eligible firms, as discussed in subsection 3.2. of our pre-analysis plan (published here) and by anticlique (as defined in appendix A of the pre-analysis plan). The likelihood of being treated differs for each each stratum.
Randomization Method
computer
Randomization Unit
taxpayer
Was the treatment clustered?
No

Experiment Characteristics

Sample size: planned number of clusters
5500 taxpayers
Sample size: planned number of observations
5,500 treated taxpayers, circa 100,000 untreated taxpayers. All observed in the administrative data from January 2021-present.
Sample size (or number of clusters) by treatment arms
5,500 treated, remaining 29,000 eligible firms as controls
Minimum detectable effect size for main outcomes (accounting for sample design and clustering)
IRB

Institutional Review Boards (IRBs)

IRB Name
Columbia University
IRB Approval Date
2020-02-04
IRB Approval Number
AAAS8400
Analysis Plan

There is information in this trial unavailable to the public. Use the button below to request access.

Request Information

Post-Trial

Post Trial Information

Study Withdrawal

There is information in this trial unavailable to the public. Use the button below to request access.

Request Information

Intervention

Is the intervention completed?
No
Data Collection Complete
Data Publication

Data Publication

Is public data available?
No

Program Files

Program Files
Reports, Papers & Other Materials

Relevant Paper(s)

Reports & Other Materials