Experimental Design Details
Supply Chain Mapping and High-Frequency Transaction Level Data
We begin by mapping out the supply chain network to identify the suppliers of a given trader who sells directly to the company (referred to as the “downstream trader”). We will then follow up with the suppliers to identify the suppliers’ suppliers, until we reach the producers. Once we have the baseline network, we will select a single main supply chain for a given downstream trader, which potentially includes other upstream traders and a farmer. This will form our trader sample and farmer sample. For this sample of traders and farmers, we will collect detailed information on quality, prices and sales through surveys and high-frequency field visit. Through high-frequency visits, we will collect transaction-level data on quality, prices and quantities. Specifically, we ask traders and farmers to keep samples of their main coffee transactions throughout the season. For each coffee sample, we ask traders and farmers to record the supplier/buyer of the transaction, price paid/received, and quantities purchased/sold. We will send the physical samples to a lab to measure quality along the following dimensions: moisture level, foreign matter, total defects, and outturn. This will allow us to have an accurate and objective measure of quality. We will also ask what quality improvement activities they have conducted.
This will allow us to document two facts: (1) typical supply chain length and structure; and (2) the quality premium (gap in price for high vs. low quality coffee) along the supply chain. Specifically, we aim to document how long supply chains are and whether quality gradients diminish up the supply chain.
Experimental Contracts
In the experimental component of this paper, we offer randomized coffee contracts. These experiments are run with both traders and farmers. Contracts vary randomly on quality (high vs. low) and quantity (three possible levels). Our contracts are based on the Becker-DeGroot-Marschak (BDM) mechanism. Specifically, we start by asking respondents for their willingness-to-accept (WTA) a contract to sell a randomized quantity and quality of coffee. Then, respondents receive a scratch card with prices in a randomized order and covered by stickers. Respondents choose a sticker to scratch off to reveal the underlying price; if the uncovered price is weakly higher than their willingness-to-accept (WTA), then the coffee producer or intermediary receives a contract for the randomized quantity and quality to be sold at the uncovered price. After the two weeks have elapsed, we return and purchase the coffee if it meets the quantity and quality specified in the contract. This approach has two benefits. First, conditional on respondents’ WTA, whether they win the contract is random (i.e. based on the scratched off price); this induces random variation in whether the contract is offered. Second, we can use the resulting induced exogenous shift in quantity, along with the WTA price, to identify agents’ underlying cost structure, which we allow to vary by quality type and by upstream vs. downstream agents. This will allow us to identify costs and markdowns at different points in the supply chain and by quality type, which will give insight into whether imperfect competition or productive substitutability is driving the declining quality gradient along the supply chain.