Experimental Design Details
Since each subject must enter a survey code, we can link their survey responses back to administrative records (including, but not limited to, whether they filed a protest in 2022 or in any of the previous years).
We want to measure how the information provided inside the survey affected the subsequent decisions to file a protest. The main focus of our information-provision experiment is not to investigate if providing information (relative to not providing information) has an effect on the average probability of protesting. When provided with the information, some individuals may update their beliefs down and others may update the beliefs up, so those effects may cancel each other out. Instead, our main focus is to measure the causal effects on beliefs, by exploiting how individuals update relative to their prior beliefs. With that goal in mind, we will use econometric models and robustness checks used in some of our previous work such as:
Cullen, Z. and Perez-Truglia, R. (2018). How Much Does Your Boss Make? The Effects of Salary Comparisons. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 130 (3), pp. 766-822
Nathan, B.; Perez-Truglia, R. and Zentner, A. (2020). My Taxes are Too Darn High: Why Do Households Protest their Taxes? NBER Working Paper No. 27816.
Giaccobasso, M.; Nathan, B.; Perez-Truglia, R. and Zentner, A. (2022). Where Do My Tax Dollars Go? Tax Morale Effects of Perceived Government Spending. NBER Working Paper No. 29789.
Bottan, N. and Perez-Truglia, R. (2020). Betting on the House: Subjective Expectations and Market Choices. NBER Working Paper No. 27412.
We elicit beliefs on, and provide information about, three topics:
1) The share of households who filed a protest among the richest-1% of households.
2) The expected savings from filing a protest.
3) The share of households who filed a protest among households that are similar to the respondent's household (within $50K of the respondent's own home value).
The main hypothesis is the "trickle-down tax avoidance": the higher the perception of the share of the richest-1% households who file tax appeals, the higher the likelihood that the respondent files a appeal. This is precisely why we measure belief 1) above.
The other two beliefs are intended to disentangle causal mechanisms.
One potential mechanism is that when finding out that the richest-1% of households are likely to protest, respondents infer from that information that they could be saving more money if they protested themselves. In other words, households may think that if the richest-1% protest, it must be because filing a protest is the financially smart thing to do. The belief in 2) above is intended to disentangle this mechanism.
Another potential mechanism is that households do not care about the share of households protesting among the richest-1% specifically, but more generally about the behavior of households that are similar to them. That is, households could be reacting to the information about the richest-1% simply because they are extrapolating from that information. The belief in 3) above is intended to disentangle this second mechanism.
We have a lot of additional survey data and administrative data for heterogeneity analysis that may help to disentangle causal mechanisms. For example, we can reproduce the analysis separately for Democrat vs. Republican households or by age and race.